I'm not sure where Tobiasen gets the idea that the Austrian School is a "major school of economics." This may have been true in the 1930s, but today, at least in the academic world, it's treated (justly or not) as a fringe theory (just look through the index of any standard economics textbook for even a single mention of the names "Mises," "Hayek," "Rothbard," or "Menger"). Furthermore, the only Nobel laureate who hails from the Austrian School (as far as I am aware) is Friedrich Hayek--an impressive figure, no doubt, but still just one man.
While Tobiasen's criticisms of macroeconomic models are valid for the Keynesians, I don't think they hold very well for the Austrians. Tobiasen points out the failure of mathematically complex economic models to develop into accurate macroeconomic forecasts. Austrian models, however, are intentionally devoid of mathematics. Mises, Rothbard, and other Austrian economists spent almost as much of their time on the philosophy of economics as they did on their study of economics itself and one of the fundamental philosophical tenants of the Austrian School that they developed is that human action is too complicated to model in a mathematically precise way; a priori logical deduction is the only way to reason about economics in a meaningful way. Furthermore, the Austrian School does not make the same assumption that the Keynesians do that "people act as rational beings." The only assumption that the Austrians make is that humans act to achieve desired goals--the Austrians do not posit that humans necessarily act in a rational manner.
Hi, I'm the author of the post. First, thanks for a great comment. This is the reason I keep a blog - people like you that challenge my views and teach me (and hopefully others) things I didn't know before.
A few questions, since you seem to know the subject quite well:
- Can't it be said that the Austrian school of economics is just out of vogue? It seems like it has been swinging back and forth in popularity for the last thirty years?
- What's your take on using chaos theory, complexity and behavioral economics to model macroeconomic behaviour? It seems to me that it's on the way up.
I'm glad you enjoyed my comment! When I wrote it I had no idea it would reach the original author! As a disclaimer, I should first point out that I make no claim to knowing the subject "quite well." Economics is a hobby of mine, but my training is in astronomy.
In response to your first question, I think the status of the Austrian School in the academic economic community is quite a bit lower than "out of vogue"; the approach that the Austrian School takes toward the study of economics differs substantially from the mainstream economic community. Modern economics tries very hard to be a "real science"--it creates models, makes predictions, collects data, and sees if the data match the predictions made by the model. And the mainstream academic community has done pretty well with most of this process. The only part they seem to have a lot of trouble with is matching the data to the predictions. Unfortunately, macroeconomic data is influenced by so many factors that it is devilishly difficult to isolate the effect of a single variable. An economist who argues that a variable x has a particular effect will be met with arguments by ten other economists that, no, in fact, the data indicate that it was variables y, z, and omega. Essentially, the mainstream economic community has developed economics into a process of inductive reasoning--collect data and use the data to reason out what's going on.
The Austrians reject this methodology. Because macroeconomic data is influenced by so many different variables (millions of people acting in millions of different ways for millions of different reasons), they claim that it is simply impossible to draw any meaningful conclusions from macroeconomic data--in essence, you see in it whatever you want to see. Instead of inductive reasoning, Austrians turn to deductive reasoning. Thus, Austrians see economics as a subject closer to mathematics than to science. (Though, as I mentioned in my first comment, the Austrians reject mathematical argument as being inadequate to model the complexities of human action; Austrian reasoning is primarily verbal, which draws criticism from the mainstream academic community of being too imprecise to be useful.)
The issue is deeper than the current fashionable theory of economics. In the 1920s and 1930s the Austrian School held a respectable position with mainstream economists. At the time economics was as much deductive as inductive, so the two schools of thought were on equal footing. But as the Keynesians developed their mathematical models, economics became heavily inductive and began to see the Austrian methodology as unscientific. Ever since, various other schools of thought have enjoyed popularity, but the fundamental methodology hasn't changed. Of course, the recent failures of the mainstream economic community to predict this crisis and the success of Peter Schiff in predicting it has brought renewed interest to the Austrian School. I'm not sure, however, that even this will be sufficient to change the fundamental approach taken by the mainstream economic community. As you wrote in your post, "old habits die hard."
In response to your second question, I think that behavioral economics will be useful for the study of human psychology and, to a lesser extent, microeconomics, but I'm not convinced that it will be terribly useful for modeling macroeconomic behavior. Behavorial economics studies what small groups of humans do in very specific laboratory conditions. How well the conclusions from these experiments extend to the real world where millions of humans are doing in a wide variety of conditions is impossible to say--it's just not something that can really be tested.
Chaos theory, similarly, I believe will be quite useful in limited contexts. Chaos theory is very good at telling us what, in general, a system will do over a long time period. But it does not provide much information as to what the system will do at any particular time. More importantly, chaos theory does not shed much light on the question of why the system behaves as it does. In any science, predicting outcomes is important, but it is always secondary to understanding the system. We study science to understand the world; we make predictions to verify that our understanding of the world is correct. At the root of things, understanding why the world works as it does is the important part and chaos theory cannot provide you a priori with that explanation.
For the Austrian School, I think the study of complexity theory might hold some promise. In essence, what Austrian economists have argued since the days of Ludwig von Mises is that the problem of macroeconomic modeling is undecidable. It has (to my knowledge) never been proven, but if it were, it would make a compelling case for the Austrian methodology.
One minor nit to pick with your otherwise excellent post. It's "philosophical tenets" not "philosophical tenants", tenet and tenant do come from the same root tenere -- to hold. But tenet is an axiom that the holder believes to be true and a tenant is one who holds the property of another.
Philosophical tenants often have trouble paying the rent; but philosophical tenets are like zucchini, everyone wants to share them with you.
We're doing the Keynesian thing again because during the last couple of economic disasters, the "throw more shit at the fan 'til it starts spinning again" approach gave many people the vague impression that it might be working. Interestingly, the idea violates the basic economic assertion that nothing can be truly free. The problem is that this approach is essentially a laxative. If you have an otherwise sound economy in which value flows have for some reason stopped, you administer the laxative, wait a while, and hopefully the economy comes back.
In an unfortunate turn of events, the world's economists (and worse, the politicians who listen to them) have mistaken a laxative for a panacea: the cure to all ills! This laxative is regularly administered as a cure for influenza, mumps, and boils on the nose, among others. Often, the mumbo-jumbo and rattle-shaking and hoodoo accompanying this administration is quite convincing; and when the ill departs of its own accord, as most do, patients and doctors both are ecstatic that their trusty laxative has cured another case of tendonitis.
Why a laxative, you ask? It's simple - we have discovered (rather ingeniously) that the best indicator of the patient's health is the amount of crap they are able to produce! More laxative, more crap - healthy patient.
At the moment, we are suffering from rather severe dehydration, prompted by a hangover and now worsened by the effects of our charlatan doctors. We don't need laxatives, we need water. In particular, we need intelligent decisions about allocating available capital. Flooding the market with "artificial capital" is not the way to obtain those intelligent decisions. The patient is parched, and we're administering laxatives and diuretics. It's bad medicine.
Just because there are two schools of thought that disagree it doesn't mean that nobody knows.
Regarding the great depression, in the wikipedia article you link to, it says that the Austrian explanation is expansion of money supply not "fall of money supply".
By the way Austrian economics is not mainstream. Mainstream economics is Keynesian.
What governments are doing is following the Keynesian recommendations. The Austrian school points out the flaws of the the recommendations. They predict the failures of these measures and are ignored or ridiculed (Peter Schiff for instance). The Austrian predictions then come true. Then what do governments do? Follow the Keynesian recommendations again.
Well, if your culture tells you that a drought is because the gods are angry, and you must dance to bring the rains again, and you dance and the rains do not come -- you must not have danced enough yet. Dance more, and eventually the rains will return. It's always worked before.
While Tobiasen's criticisms of macroeconomic models are valid for the Keynesians, I don't think they hold very well for the Austrians. Tobiasen points out the failure of mathematically complex economic models to develop into accurate macroeconomic forecasts. Austrian models, however, are intentionally devoid of mathematics. Mises, Rothbard, and other Austrian economists spent almost as much of their time on the philosophy of economics as they did on their study of economics itself and one of the fundamental philosophical tenants of the Austrian School that they developed is that human action is too complicated to model in a mathematically precise way; a priori logical deduction is the only way to reason about economics in a meaningful way. Furthermore, the Austrian School does not make the same assumption that the Keynesians do that "people act as rational beings." The only assumption that the Austrians make is that humans act to achieve desired goals--the Austrians do not posit that humans necessarily act in a rational manner.