Hacker News new | past | comments | ask | show | jobs | submit login
How Mondragon Became the World's Largest Co-Op (newyorker.com)
137 points by mitchbob on Aug 27, 2022 | hide | past | favorite | 68 comments



The dynamics of Mondragon participating in free trade are no different than any other corporate entity. The internal dynamic works because most people that are participating share the same core values of shared ownership, and there is no corporate ladder to climb. IMO, leadership making these values core to the business is going against the grain, putting your probability of survival below or equal to that of others, which is why they are a rare occurrence

It's objectively a better model for ensuring the sustainability of a corporation, with respect to operating in a free market. I would say that being an employee at a high productivity co op is the same as being a highly skilled software developer working for a contracting firm or maybe a sizeable startup. You have a valuable impact and have skin in the game.

I think there is a tipping point where greed can end a corporation, but e.g. for western corporations, the beast is fed by central banking. The problem with that, is that there are clear winners that are chosen, which go on to buy out their competition. At that point, you have management making working conditions less and less favorable, for the sake of share holder bottom line, to the point of societal unrest. Take a look at Amazon.


But do high productivity / high demand employees earn outsized compensation? Software engineers at Uber, for example, earn probably 10x what drivers make. If you look at some of the recent ridesharing coop attempts in the US, they advertise wages of 70-80k for devs, which is just not going to work in a competitive market.


Generally you won't find investors pouring millions into co-op because investors do this in expectation of ownership and control -- the opposite of what they get in a co-op. So it's harder for a co-op to raise the ridiculous amounts of money they need to pay outsized compensation.

Instead, part of the compensation package is to not be beholden to corporate overlords and quarterly report-driven shareholder value-based crap. I'm absolutely willing to take a financial pay cut for that.


I'd say the number of people willing to take a 5x paycut (it is literally 5x) for feeling better about themselves is pretty small. The number of those people who are qualified to work on matching algorithms and pricing algorithms is even smaller. And you need matching and pricing algorithms to compete against Uber and Lyft, because they can price discriminate (e.g. airport rides) against consumers and get better utilization out of drivers, so if they have to compete, they can pay drivers more than you.


> I'd say the number of people willing to take a 5x paycut (it is literally 5x) for feeling better about themselves is pretty small

What do you suppose is the median salary for devs in the US? Tech salaries are increasingly bimodal, take care not to be deceived by big tech/bay area salaries.


Sure, but then you are hiring less skilled talent that is probably incapable of working on pricing and matching algorithms (which along with scale are the real advantage Uber has, since everyone can make a crappy iOS app and call it a day).

If the algorithms didn't matter then Uber wouldn't be maintaining 70% marketshare in the US.

Also, a quick look at levels.fyi says salary at IBM (i.e. your median salary dev) for a senior is 192k. Compared to 80k for a ridesharing coop, that's still quite the salary cut. Don't forget a lot of these coops are based in HCOL areas like NYC.


> Sure, but then you are hiring less skilled talent that is probably incapable of working on pricing and matching algorithms

This sounds like a variation of the just world fallacy to me: in a just world, talented folk who solve hard problems get paid more, and the less talented ones - who are unable to solve hairy problems - get paid less. In such a world, you can identify the talented ones by how much they are earning. Yet in the real world, geography, and luck/ability to bootstrap to HCOL areas plays a huge part

> Also, a quick look at levels.fyi says salary at IBM (i.e. your median salary dev) for a senior is 192k.

I think you're underestimating how wide the gap is between the bimodal peaks. $192 is too high[2] still; it slots just below Senior executive average ($200k) and right above EM ($180k) in the 2022 StackOverflow salary survey[1] for the US

1. https://survey.stackoverflow.co/2022/#work-salary

2. the survey doesn't distinguish between junior & senior engineers, but I'm guessing even the seniors earn less than CxO's.


Your survey seems very flawed. It puts an average SRE at 175k yet the CxO's only make 200k. Are you sure you're not excluding stock based comp in those numbers?

In any case, even if you go by the data in your survey, a machine learning specialist is supposed to make 150k and a mobile developer 144k. Those are still a lot more than 70-80k.

> Yet in the real world, geography, and luck/ability to bootstrap to HCOL areas plays a huge part

Considering the bar to get into a FAANG is just 4-5 leetcode medium-hard questions, I think there is little gatekeeping happening. This isn't investment banking where if you don't go to an Ivy you can't get in. And there are a lot more firms than FAANG paying big salaries.

> I think you're underestimating how wide the gap is between the bimodal peaks

IBM is your quintessential example of a consulting bodyshop. If anything, they would be at the lower bimodal peak, not the higher one.


> Your survey seems very flawed. It puts an average SRE at 175k yet the CxO's only make 200k.

My guess is the sample of SREs in the survey is biased towards start-ups & big tech (thats were that role is common), where as CEOs samples have less of that bias.

> Are you sure you're not excluding stock based comp in those numbers?

Yes I'm sure! I'm surprised that you're surprised - the average developer does not get stock-based comp because they are not working at big tech or a start up. "Enterprise software" shops & Small-to-medium businesses do not generally offer stock/options to employees


Won't it work though? The market isn't full of rational salary optimizing actors, there are some (probably a small percentage) that care more about their work env and culture than salary. This might be either because they already feel they have enough money or simply hate the normal corporate culture.


Ideally the pay cut would be smaller than he expense of buying antidepressants and regular therapist visits.


I don't know about you but I'd rather not spend years of my life sedated on drugs just for money. There are places to live outside the states that don't require you to make 100k per year to have a very good life.


Exactly my point.

A soul-crushing job may be not worth it just from the financial perspective.


That's 80k + a share, which may have a lot of value.


Though you have to buy that share.


It’s usually progressively deduced from your salary, you don’t need to buy it upfront


At least in this case, it sounds like you buy it upfront.

> Mondragon’s co-ops share the same detailed information with worker-owners, who buy into their co-ops by making one-time payments of roughly sixteen thousand euros in most co-ops.


I'm sure Mondragon's financing coöp will happily assist with funding a loan, underwritten by an insurance coöp and paid through the bank coöp. It's turtles^w coöps all the way down.


> IMO, leadership making these values core to the business is going against the grain, putting your probability of survival below or equal to that of others, which is why they are a rare occurrence

The rarity of co-ops is definitely not from survival rates, because they completely trash regular businesses in that regard:

> A 2013 report published by the UK Office for National Statistics showed that in the UK the rate of survival of cooperatives after five years was 80 percent compared with only 41 percent for all other enterprises.[5] A further study found that after ten years 44 percent of cooperatives were still in operation, compared with only 20 percent for all enterprises.

> In a 2007 study by the World Council of Credit Unions, the five-year survival rate of cooperatives in the United States was found to be 90% in comparison to 3-5% for traditional businesses.

(This figure seems kind of hard to believe... Maybe there's some self-selection bias in that people in the US might be much more willing to personally risk starting any number of different kinds of businesses for themselves and at most one, maybe two others, whereas they might only be willing to start a co-op with multiple other people if it looks like a pretty sure thing with a well-established model?)

> A 2010 report by the Ministry of Economic Development, Innovation and Export in Québec found that the five-year survival rate and ten-year survival rate of cooperatives in Québec to be 62% and 44% respectively compared to 35% and 20% for conventional firms.[53] Another report by the BC-Alberta Social economy Research Alliance found that the three-year survival rate of cooperatives in Alberta to be 81.5% in comparison to 48% for traditional firms.

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Cooperative#Economic_stability

There are probably many reasons why co-ops are rarer, but the obvious one of relevance to the startup community is that you wouldn't start a co-op if you were hoping to make tons and tons of money rather than a "merely" reasonable income.


Co-ops are rarer for three reasons, chiefly:

1. Less access to capital. Investors want to exchange capital for ownership. Co-ops oppose this model. There are alternative methods for raising cash (subordinated capital campaigns are a successful example), but banks are conservative in nature and are just not eager to underwrite things they aren't very familiar with.

2. Discriminatory taxation. Are co-op member-owners to be taxed at the earned income rate, the capital gains rate, or both? The IRS has intentionally left this unclear and repeatedly refused to give strong guidance, putting co-ops at a distinct disadvantage in paying members and structuring membership.

3. Consistent legal structure. Unlike with the relatively standardized form of the limited liability corporation, the definition of the legal corporate form for co-ops varies widely between states and countries. This lack of standardization makes each incorporation process a custom, costly, time-intensive exercise.

I am of the opinion that cooperatives are a superior legal structure to LLCs for lots of reasons internal and external to the firm. But until these core problems are addressed, cooperatives will remain relatively rare, despite their many advantages.


Two hypotheses.

- Many companies are tiny, created to pursue a small idea as a side project, and to optimize taxes while doing so. Certainly most of such companies close quickly and likely painlessly.

- Companies more often go for high-risk, high-reward projects that a co-op won't touch. This self-selects co-ops into the niches of stable, long-term, lower-risk business.


I've looked into the history of Mondragon and what is often overlooked is the fact that their credit union could legally offer higher interest rates to depositors than competing banks. So they were able to accumulate the capital needed to finance their operations and expansion somewhat unfairly. If you wonder why there aren't more Mondragons in the world do more research on the history of Caja Laboral Popular.


I wouldn't quite call it "unfair". Credit unions worldwide tend to offer higher savings rates because they distribute their profits to depositors as interest yield instead of to shareholders as dividends.


This is a very strange argument, because banks do not lend out deposits.

Deposits are created jointly with each new loan on its balance (and destroyed when the loan pays back).

Offering higher deposits is actually a higher cost for a bank and lowers its profitability.


> This is a very strange argument, because banks do not lend out deposits.

Deposits absolutely drive how much a bank can loan though. Otherwise banks wouldn’t bother taking deposits at all.

Look at the history of what the Narrow Bank attempted to do. It tried to drop the whole loan side of the business and effectively offer the fed funds rate directly to depositors. They were rejected because it was detrimental to the whole ecosystem of loans.


Could you elaborate on why that higher interest rate is unfair?


They didn't claim that the higher interest rate is unfair per se. They're claiming that the regulators allowing Mondragon to have exclusive monopoly access to the high interest rate market is what's unfair.


I've spent a whole day reading up on this company a while ago, it is super interesting as a possible alternative way of working. The fact that they have managed to scale it up as far as they did is what really impresses me.

I wonder how well it would work if you started something like this from scratch today in for instance SV.


I think this sort of thing is nigh impossible to do these days in most parts of the world. If you look at most major cooperatives around the world, almost all of them were founded at least 60-70 years ago if not further out.

The primary challenge imo is the mass financialization of the global economy, which makes it a lot more enticing to start a traditional corporation over a cooperative. Cooperative regulations in most jurisdictions make it very difficult to raise equity and even restrict many types of debt. There’s more coordination overhead, at least initially, and once mature, most cooperatives tend to look like public companies governance-wise anyway.

It just doesn’t make sense for the average person to start their own cooperative, especially in any competitive domain. The risk-to-reward ratio is totally skewed towards the wrong direction. It’s like starting a union for a non-existing company.

I say all this as an avid cooperatist who has been working in the space for the last six years and who runs a cooperative startup in Quebec, arguably one of the strongest coop ecosystems in the world. If the stars didn’t align for us (e.g. strong technical team, ample personal funds, prior cooperative experience, market timing, etc.), there’s no way we’d be surviving two years in.


>It just doesn’t make sense for the average person to start their own cooperative, especially in any competitive domain.

What do you mean by 'competitive domain'? State of the art like Amazon or many competitors like Ben and Jerry's [1]?

If it's competitive like Ben and Jerry's, wouldn't that be the best environment for a cooperative? You can use your network to assemble an initial team and then build something that the market wants because everybody already knows the market. You create one more offer that will find its niche on the market.

Where else does an average person have enough domain knowledge to make a better investment?

[1] https://www.joelonsoftware.com/2000/05/12/strategy-letter-i-...


I’d qualify both scenarios as being competitive, though arguably the Ben and Jerry’s one is likely easier for the “average” person to break into with a cooperative.

While the capital requirements are relatively lower to start a food processing business, they’re not non-existent. The founders will have to pony up most of the initial investment and take on a whole lot of risk early on, with only a very slim possibility of a large payout if the venture does exceedingly well. Most financial institutions (even cooperative ones) won’t lend to them, as it’s difficult to collateralize the initial equity put forth by the founders of a cooperative. Equity can’t be issued to investors, due to governance and legal restrictions. The capital pool is thus dramatically constrained vis-à-vis a traditional corporation.

This is ignoring that cooperatives are harder to start in most jurisdictions due to a lack of legal resources. Our food delivery cooperative took 7 months and several letters and in-person meetings to legally incorporate (even though we started sales one month in) whereas our local competitors who formed corporations were able to incorporate within one day and online. During the early months of the pandemic, we actually had to get a derogation from the government to be the first cooperative in Canada to have our founding general assembly (a legal requirement to start a cooperative in Quebec) online, as the law said we all to physically meet in person to be able to incorporate!

The very legal framework for cooperatives see much less use in most jurisdictions, meaning that when things go wrong, the venues for recourse are unclear due to a lack of precedent. A notable case of this is the hijacking/bankruptcy of Mountain Equipment Co-op in Vancouver, Canada, which was sold off to private equity without the consent of its members, all while following the law to the letter.

Contrast this with starting a corporation, where the financing and governance playbook is known and if you want to bring in more people onto the team, you can just continue subdividing the equity to get something akin to a cooperative. A cooperative is just a corporation after all, just with a more equitable equity split.

I think what you’re suggesting can still work in certain cultural and economic environments. The founders really have to sell the idea of buying into their cooperative, all while limiting their potential upside as they bring in members who have yet to contribute to the cooperative and yet will soon be eligible to take part in the proceeds and governance. If they can manage that and get over the initial legal and financial hurdles, they can totally be competitive. The initial constraints don’t make it attractive however.


> It just doesn’t make sense for the average person to start their own cooperative, especially in any competitive domain. The risk-to-reward ratio is totally skewed towards the wrong direction.

This is really insightful and almost fully explains why there aren't more co-ops. Entrepreneurship AND capital aren't being materially rewarded for the huge amount of risk, so both founders and investors have zero interest in trying out the model, unless they're unusually missionary minded about the co-op model. That's two factors of production out the window. I think this is why market socialists often advocate for the government to ban traditional shareholder-owned corporations and force everyone into the co-op model, with capital allocation initially handled by a government bureaucracy. Founders and investors actually can't get there voluntarily due to high risk receiving little reward.


Spot-on and reflects the reality I’ve been living for the past two years.


I have questions about this model.

How are terminations of underperforming employees handled?

Is there a particular type of business (e.g. established old-school industry vs. R&D startup) where this model should be better at, and others where it is worse at, due to systematic factors?

Does a worker co-op mean that a union serves no purpose?

Would a worker co-op mean that important strategic decisions are made by large committees, or can they made by individual/executives that are voted into their position by workers? Or are such details up to the discretion of the particular co-op's charter?

How does it differ to a traditional company that simply gives lots of equity to all the employees? Is the main practical difference that the "equity" (i.e. their voting power and profit share) expires when the employee quits their job, and therefore it isn't commoditized?

Would this model be expected to produce less externalities to society? Or should the same bad incentives cause them to pollute, corrupt government, and so on?

Clearly, something is holding back worker co-ops from competing effectively in the market, given that examples like Mondragon are relatively rare. What are all the reasons for this?


Often the person able to formulate such well thought questions Is the only person being able to research and answer them :-)


These are great questions and it'd be impossible to answer then all here satisfactorily. I'd recommend the book "Making Mondragón" for more in depth analysis of labor relations at the company, especially during the transition to the globalized economy.

In short:

1. Underperforming workers can still be fired. Their ownership stake is bought out by the firm. Because firings are costly, hiring is a more intentional process, typically involving a "trial period" at the beginning of employment that more closely resembles traditional employment (no ownership stake, no voting rights, easy severance).

2. Successful cooperatives exist in all sectors, but there are many variables at play. A tech worker co-op today is unlikely to be able to pay its worker-owners salaries comparable to what VC can provide, due to factors ranging from tax rates (capital is taxed at negligible rates compared to labor) to investment bubbles and concentration of wealth. Long-lasting cooperatives have lasted longest in agriculture and finance because they can operate more efficiently than firms which need to retain a chunk of their margin to pay investors.

3. There is no real role for a union in a worker co-op. Surprisingly, this doesn't mean they don't exist. Mondragón actually went to war against unionizing efforts at their firm in the 80s, which led to them increasing education on what rights and privileges worker-owners already have. Generally, though, worker co-ops align the incentives of workers with the firm such that unions are unnecessary.

4. The management structure of each cooperative is up to them. Most successful ones (including Mondragón) delegate decision-making to a core group of elected executives, just like in successful modern democracies. Major structural decisions are made by general assembly -- analogous to a stockholder meeting at joint stock firms.

5. Worker co-ops differ from ESOPs (firms that grant lots of equity to workers) in that they confer decision-making, as well as equity, to workers. ESOPs usually grant workers non-voting shares. I've actually seen the ugly side of ESOPs when my startup employer diluted my stake to nearly nothing just prior to a buyout. That would be a much more difficult prospect in a worker co-op.

6. I'm unaware of any systematic studies done on the relative propensity for different types of firms to externalize costs. I'd only say that there's certainly less incentive for worker co-ops to act irresponsibly, as they are directly answerable to their community, who both work at and own the firm, and usually live nearby.

And there's no obvious way in which they seem more incentivised to bad behavior than other types of firms.

For example, Mondragón were "caught" underpaying some workers in their overseas factories, in line with how other firms abuse their outsourced workforce. However, they were caught by their own worker-owners, and unlike other companies, Mondragón's worker-owners objected to this treatment and voted to provide their outsourced employees with a path to full ownership.

7. I've responded elsewhere with what's holding worker co-ops back and won't elaborate too much here. Suffice it to say that they would be much more common if there was a standard corporate form, consistent and non-discriminatory tax treatment, and and easier access to alternative means of raising capital.

Where some or all of these structures are in place, cooperatives are surprisingly common. I'd advise looking into the Emilia-Romagna region of Italy, in addition to Basque Spain for more examples.


> 6. I'm unaware of any systematic studies done on the relative propensity for different types of firms to externalize costs. I'd only say that there's certainly less incentive for worker co-ops to act irresponsibly, as they are directly answerable to their community, who both work at and own the firm, and usually live nearby.

That makes sense. Externalities will be less. I would love to hear how anarcho-syndicalists think that any remaining externalities can be managed without a state. Like, if I'm in a co-op with 10 people, I can still see us all deciding to screw over society just a little bit for our own gain, and telling ourselves a nice story that that's not what's happening.

> 7. I've responded elsewhere with what's holding worker co-ops back and won't elaborate too much here. Suffice it to say that they would be much more common if there was a standard corporate form, consistent and non-discriminatory tax treatment, and and easier access to alternative means of raising capital.

Don't both capital and entrepreneurship require asymmetric compensation for the unusual amount of risk of starting some ventures? Even if the playing field was levelled, why would a founder or investor willingly opt-in to a corporate form that will massively reduce their upside in the 10% chance that they end up succeeding? I could see why they would do it for a traditional business -- say, they're a group of 5 plumbers that start a co-op together, where some level of success is guaranteed and they don't project needing to hire 1000 additional employees that will dilute their upside as the business matures. But what about the far more risky (both capital intensiveness and probability of success) ventures, e.g. starting a nuclear fusion company? For these sectors I can only see two viable solutions: (1) accept that co-ops can't service these particular high risk sectors properly due to a fundamentally inadequate incentives, or (2) government becomes a VC firm and the traditional corporate form is banned.


> That makes sense. Externalities will be less. I would love to hear how anarcho-syndicalists think that any remaining externalities can be managed without a state. Like, if I'm in a co-op with 10 people, I can still see us all deciding to screw over society just a little bit for our own gain, and telling ourselves a nice story that that's not what's happening.

States are here to stay and are, in fact, necessary for the enforcement and arbitration of business law. They're a necessary ingredient to any regulatory regime.

I look askance at any solution that pretends to completely "solve" the issue of externalities. Humans are optimizing, externalizing creatures, and our organizations will reflect that fact.

Given all that, though, an ecosystem of cooperatives actually does do a better job of policing and creatively regulating externalities in a manner more beneficial to society than many forms of government regulation.

This is because governments are susceptible to regulatory capture by private capital, and the concentration of wealth into relatively fewer hands only exacerbates this problem. Cooperatives actively fight against the unfair concentration of wealth, and an ecosystem of cooperatives forms a network of reinforcing relationships that find opportunity in waste that private capital firms might otherwise externalize to the public to deal with.

A good example might be the worker-owned retirement homes in northern Italy. Staff earn higher wages -- and care is consistently rated as far better -- than at either for-profit or public facilities.

> Don't both capital and entrepreneurship require asymmetric compensation for the unusual amount of risk of starting some ventures?

Sure, but that's not incompatible with cooperative ownership. There are forms of worker co-ops which give greater ownership stakes to workers who contribute more, take on early risk, or have seniority. It's not binary.

There are cooperatives that look indistinguishable from SV startups. The only major exception is that they grant voting stock to new hires instead of non-voting share options.

> Even if the playing field was levelled, why would a founder or investor willingly opt-in to a corporate form that will massively reduce their upside in the 10% chance that they end up succeeding?

Because the odds of a cooperative succeeding are higher than with LLCs and joint stock companies (see upthread and numerous studies). In other words, many people would be more willing to accept a 50% smaller slice of the pie if the odds of success triple.

Another minor point here: Cooperative structures also have an advantage in sustainable longevity. VC-funded companies are exit-oriented and tend to struggle to settle into enriching, viable companies post-exit. Cooperatives offer a competitive advantage to the entrepreneur who is not looking to pump-and-dump their life's work, but instead build a sustainable business in the long term. All things being equal, workers will overwhelmingly prefer to work at a mature firm for ownership than simply for wages.

> But what about the far more risky (both capital intensiveness and probability of success) ventures, e.g. starting a nuclear fusion company?

Interestingly, that's not too dissimilar from what Mondragón was at its inception -- a capital-intensive, high risk business. And there are actually lots of cooperatives that succeed at these margins around the world. They're just not easy to start in the US due to a blend of factors including culture, concentration of wealth, and hostile regulations.

But I'd like to point out that, even if the answer is "accept that co-ops can't service these particular high risk sectors properly due to a fundamentally inadequate incentives," nobody in the cooperative space is advocating the eradication of joint stock companies or other corporate forms. Cooperatives are not a one-size-fits-all solution. There will always be cases when LLCs, LLPs, JSCs, etc are a more appropriate form. We just want more choice.

I would strongly support a federal law defining a standard cooperative corporate form and giving worker cooperatives preferential treatment under the tax code. I think society could only benefit from such a change.

At worst, we'd see a bunch of new cooperatives pop up on the fringes, where they had previously been too onerous to start or operate. At best, we'd see a much more democratic economy across the board, with workers more invested in the success of their firms and firms more accountable to their workers.


Awesome response. Any thoughts on what happened with Yugoslavia's experience with co-ops?


I actually live in Croatia these days and have some experience with zadruge (Yugoslav cooperatives). Many of the agricultural cooperatives still survive, but the worker cooperatives were largely converted into joint stock corporations in the early 90s and then asset stripped by private equity and crooked politicians for a decade or two thereafter.

Several family members worked at zadruge and that's where I get most of my information from, so take this all with a grain of salt...

One of the key issues with zadruge was that, while nominally cooperatives, they were actually owned and managed by the state. Directors were appointed by the communist party and not elected by the workers. As a result, a culture of kleptocracy crept in, since party rank and connections were more beneficial than seniority or hard work, and resentment grew between labor and management.

This has tainted the idea of cooperatives in the former Yugoslavia, so few people are interested in reviving cooperatives today, even though the core issues that plagued zadruge have improved dramatically since 1991.

They were, however, an experiment in democracy in the workplace, albeit limited. And that was radical for its time. Most people I've spoken with say that, for all their failings, zadruge were enriching and empowering places to work and much preferred alternatives to today's jobs.


I started thinking about this kind of structure after coming across this company making climbing equipment. I think there is something valuable to it, maybe not necessarily for every type of business. Among friends recently there has been some discussion about the fake-ness of businesses saying we're a family while treating people/employees as relatively disposable. This is a bit of a large scale way to address that.

https://www.totemmt.com/about-us/

"We are a Cooperative Work company from Basque Country. Our mission is to supply the climbers community with quality protection gear.

The production is entirely made in Hernani (Gipuzkoa). We focus our efforts to improve the production processes and management systems to achieve what is demanded by the customer: good products, competitive price and on time delivery."


Nothing stops anyone from structuring a new business like this. Many professional service firms such as private medical clinics and law firms are structured as partnerships, which is a co-operative type of entity.

The tricky thing is building a product-focused business like this. The risk-reward ratio is very different. Most fail and few succeed massively. Succeeding massively often requires extreme hard work and ingenuity from top employees.

Personally I would never work at, nor invest any money, in a co-op. Same reason I will never invest in a public benefit corporation. I don’t see the economy as charity and I prefer to donate money to overtly non-profit entities rather than donating to “I am willing to make you less money” for-profit entities.


> I don’t see the economy as charity and I prefer to donate money to overtly non-profit entities rather than donating to “I am willing to make you less money” for-profit entities.

Somewhat counterintuitively, "I am willing to make less money" can be unusually effective, if the difference in how much money you're making is small enough. The intuition is that in non-fully-competitive settings, the creation of quasi-rents has quadratic costs on the economy as a whole, much like any other tax. So giving up a tiny bit of quasi-rent in an elastic market has outsized positive effects.


You wouldn’t work at or invest in Etsy, Veeva, Coursera, Kickstarter, Patagonia, or Warby Parker?


Correct


Many open source projects are practically run as co-ops, though often not for profit. I guess open source doesn't start specifically in Silicon Valley, but it's in the computer software space at least.


Sadly, I think folks in SV have other priorities (at least ostensibly). You have to give up seeking gold to find life's other treasures, or something :)


People think co-ops are a hippy thing but MasterCard was a co-op of financial institutions:

https://en.m.wikipedia.org/wiki/Mastercard

I'd suggest many corporate open source efforts, like AV1 or Android and Linux are similar structures and follow a similar pattern of one corporation having an early dominance, and the other corporations facing the choice of standing together or losing individually.


Many of the most successful agricultural, banking, and insurance firms are cooperatives. They have a number of advantages over other corporate forms, but suffer from a legislative and regulatory environment that has become increasingly discriminatory against them.


There was a nice discussion on Mondragon, and co-ops in general, in Kim Stanley Robinson's recent book Ministry for the Future.

That book is chock full of ideas - a fun read!


A co-op like Mondragon but global in scope is at the center of 'Islands in the Net' by Bruce Sterling.

There's a much smaller co-op at the heart of 'Shockwave Rider' by John Brunner, but discussion of the mechanics is central to the story. This is an incredible book.


That and Sheep Look Up were my genesis. Kinda opposite to the Atlas Shrugged and Heinlein stuff that seemed to captivate most of my peers.


So much of Stand on Zanzibar captures the tone of the modern age well, and some of the details too.


They also feature heavily in his mars trilogy


The issue is that successful co-ops take work to build. Most early promoters of a business are seeking financial compensation. In Mondragon's case they had religious fervor. There's actually quite a few Catholic 'co-ops' that are founded because it is part of Catholic belief.

While we don't often think of it that way, the Knights of Columbus in the United States has as its main purpose, the pooling of resources to provide for working class male members (which number in the millions). It still runs one of the largest not-for-profit life insurance schemes in the country [1]. While not a 'co-op' in the sense of Mondragon, it does provide the social security net that he Mondragon founders set up.

So honestly, I think for established co-ops you need some kind of religious fervor. That is true of these co-ops, or also the communist hippy ones, except there's a different religion. Other successful examples of co-ops, like Winco, are where employees later purchase a private business from owners, rather than being established as a co-op.

[1] And provides a whole host of other benefits for its members.


I remember reading a lot about Mondragon a few years ago. I don't remember the specifics but my takeaway was that it is not so different than a regular corporation. The idealized co-op only really exists in organizations where everyone does close to the same job, if fruit picking. There are some examples of such co-ops in the US.


Take a look at Suma in the UK - a large coop with £50 million turn over. Not everyone does the same job, but everyone gets the same pay, much more like an idealized co-op.



The world's largest Co-Op?

What does "Co-Op" means in this context? Because if it was under ordinary Co-Op, I am pretty sure there are a few Co-Op larger than Mondragon.

> "In 2021, the network brought in more than eleven billion euros in revenue"

€11B, or roughly $11B USD in revenue. There are quite a few large Co-Op in Japan unknown to the West, which is similar or an order of magnitude larger. But outside of that, even the well known ones from New Zealand such as Fonterra, I guess everyone should at least have heard of the butter brand Anchor, comes in at 20.57 billion NZD revenue, or ~$12.5B USD.

So what makes Mondragon the largest Co-Op in the world? By Profits? By Headcounts? or By Asset?


Mondragon is a worker co-op, Fonterra is a dairy co-op, which is a type of producer co-op. So I think they mean that Mondragon is the largest worker co-op in the world.


Mondragons as an economic model are also referenced in Kim Stanley Robinson's Red/Green/Blue Mars novel series


I have visited and interviewed several agricultural coops (dairy and grains), some are very similar to a normal business, but the ones that are not, usually are built to solve a group's common problem, not to be financially successful by itself. Some are tied to local politics and are meant to augment public policies, some are just a channel to process and commercialize their production.


My kids go to a school which organized around as a cooperative owned by the parents. I find the biggest problem is lack of general financial understanding by people about what a cooperative is. It’s still a business and every member is on the hook for their share of the losses the business incur.

The problem as I’m all cooperatives organized around delivering a service to its owners a handful of people carry the whole load of work.


> To some critics, Mondragon’s overseas workers, who are not owners—it outsources to low-cost locations, operating a hundred and thirty-two production plants in thirty-two countries—are a sacrifice to the dragon of capitalism.

Ah of course, I knew there was a catch. Capitalism consumes all morals!


Hiring low wage workers in foreign countries is not automatically immoral under utilitarianism if the only alternative is to not hire them, in which case they will be forced to find an even worse job that objectively reduces their utility. The hypothetical alternative of Mondragon hiring foreign workers at higher wages may actually be practically impossible under our current capitalist system, given the kind of dilemma like incentives at play when separate businesses are competing to provide fungible goods to consumers who are making purchasing decisions based on which offering has the lowest price. What is immoral is the system that makes this the case: closed borders, lack of regulations protecting foreign workers in endogenous bargaining disputes, and so on.

I also dislike how this topic is weaponized by nativists, and sometimes by self-proclaimed leftists, in order to push for policies -- banning foreign labor (leftists) or closing borders and isolationism (nativists), typically -- that clearly make the lives of people in poor countries worse and not better.


Of course, I agree with your description. It’s not logical to stop hiring foreigners, or expecting Western wages - I just feel like a cooperative could come up with a better compromise.


Well, in order to join a cooperative to work, you must pay a big chunk, but you may (should?) have a guaranteed job forever. At least with Eroski, or maybe Orbea.


> you must pay a big chunk

not really, you could be given shares as part of the compensation package. Of course, paying to purchase some shares is and should be possible too.

> you may (should?) have a guaranteed job forever.

if by this you mean that if you don't work, you would still get paid your wages, then it'd be impossible. But your shares that you obtain as part of your compensation package would entitle you to some of the profits (proportional to your ownership amount), so it should be possible to receive money even if stopped working (you just don't receive a wage).

if by this you mean you can never be fired from the job, despite your poor performance, then i dont believe that it ever to be possible - perhaps you cannot have unfair dismissals (i imagine dismissals are via committee, which means other share holders, which are also your coworkers, have a say, and if they all agree to dismiss, it must mean your contributions are negative).




Guidelines | FAQ | Lists | API | Security | Legal | Apply to YC | Contact

Search: